Multi-asset

Building a regime-resistant, long-run allocation in multi asset

Building a regime-resistant, long-run allocation in multi asset
Florian Ielpo, PhD - Head of Macro, Multi Asset

Florian Ielpo, PhD

Head of Macro, Multi Asset
Julien Royer, PhD - Quantitative Analyst, Multi Asset

Julien Royer, PhD

Quantitative Analyst, Multi Asset
Selbi Muhammetgulyyeva - Investment Analyst

Selbi Muhammetgulyyeva

Investment Analyst

MARS, our Multi-Asset Research Series, focuses on complex topics in the realm of multi asset to bring quantitative investment research back to Earth. This fourth edition considers how to bridge the gap between existing approaches – the multi-regime distribution of assets and risk-parity investing – in order to optimise risk-based portfolio construction.

In financial returns, low-frequency alternating regimes make the dynamic of financial assets non-linear. Timing these regimes is at the heart of designing multi-asset portfolios. Enter the regime-parity portfolio: a new, risk-based portfolio that can improve the return-contribution balance within long-run allocations. 


Please explore the latest issue of MARS by clicking on the sections below.

  • Multi-asset portfolio construction is often split into two components: a long-run portfolio and a tactical overlay. The long-run (potentially long-only) portfolio captures the unconditional multivariate distribution of financial assets, while the tactical overlay tilts the long-run portfolio from its long-term equilibrium to adapt the final portfolio to the current regime guiding markets. 

    A well-established empirical fact in financial returns is the existence of low frequency alternating regimes making the dynamic of financial assets non-linear. For example, Maheu and McCurdy (2000) study the properties of bull and bear markets and Guidolin and Timmermann (2006) consider a three-regime framework when modelling the joint dynamics of stocks and bonds. While timing these regimes is at the heart of constructing the tactical overlay – as highlighted in Van Vliet and Blitz (2011) and Ielpo (2014) for traditional risk premia or Blin et al. (2020) for alternative risk premia – the long-run portfolio construction usually omits these regimes. Instead, it is designed to obtain an unconditionally optimal portfolio derived from the unconditional covariance-matrix. 

    After the Global Financial Crisis in 2008, some alternate approaches to the long-standing 60/40 static portfolio have emerged and attracted attention. One idea that has been explored at length is risk diversification, as opposed to more static and concentrated capital allocation schemes. The most discussed approach amongst them has been risk parity. While its popularity was at its highest a decade ago, this diversification technique has lost popularity but remains, in our view, a relevant portfolio diversification option.

    The idea of this portfolio construction is to allocate an equal weight between assets, in term of risk rather than capital, to improve diversification. However, as emphasised by Ardia et al. (2018), the resulting portfolio, although diversified in risk, tends to be concentrated in term of its contribution to the final performance-to-risk ratio (for example, the Sharpe ratio). In other words, while empirically well distributed in terms of risk, such a portfolio will become progressively over-reliant on its diversifying assets as sources of returns. 

    In this paper, we introduce a new risk-based, long-run portfolio that bridges the gap between the multi-regime distribution of assets and risk-parity investing. The first section explicitly derives this regime-parity portfolio, building upon the standard Equal Risk Contribution approach. In section 2, we illustrate the sensitivity of our allocation to different shocks; in particular we show that our portfolio construction is more resilient to structural breaks and infrequent tail-risk events. Section 3 applies our findings to different markets. The final section concludes and surveys potential future research perspectives.
     

  • Long-run portfolios are designed to harvest the long-term performance of assets. For that reason, they are often computed from the unconditional distribution of returns, enabling stable allocation while active bets are effectively concentrated in the tactical overlays. As this long-run allocation is the foundation of the portfolio, it should be diversified enough to efficiently harvest a wide range of risk premia. 

    Capital allocation is known to be deceiving from that perspective: what looks well diversified in terms of capital allocation can present a poor breakdown of risk across risk premia. For example, a standard 60/40 US equity-bond portfolio often hides highly concentrated risk in equities as the asset class accounts for more than 90% of the total portfolio risk.  This statement does not intend to judge the virtues (or not) of investing in equities, but solely highlights the fact that proper cross-asset portfolio diversification is not as simple as spreading capital between few traditional assets.

    Allocation risk, rather than capital, is a preferable solution that constructs portfolios by considering the risk contribution of each risk premia to the total portfolio risk and explicitly helps improve diversification. Cases in point are the famous risk parity or Equal Risk Contribution (ERC) portfolios introduced by Maillard et al. (2010) and Bai et al. (2016). The latter consider volatility as the risk measure while Boudt et al. (2012) generalise the risk parity to downside risk measures such as the Value-at-Risk.

    The derivation of the ERC portfolio is based on the decomposition of the total risk of the portfolio, denoted  where   denotes the capital allocation, into the individual risk contributions1:
     


     


    The ERC portfolio is thus the portfolio  such that and  . Computing individual risk contributions, which are functions of the unconditional moments of the multivariate distribution of asset returns, helps derive weights, making risk contributions equal.

    However, when the asset dynamics are regime-dependent, these unconditional moments have a tendency to crush this regime-level information, when it should inform us about the long-term behaviour of asset returns. To illustrate this inconsistency of unconditional moments, there is no better example than a mixture of Gaussian distributions. 

    Figure 1 presents two of such examples where a random variable X  follows a Gaussian mixture with equal weights between regime 1 where  and regime 2 where . Depending on the parameters of the distribution, note how the Gaussian distribution implied by the unconditional moments of X can be uninformative, failing to reveal information about the true distribution. For example, when  ,  and , the implied unconditional distribution indicates a probability of 30% for to be between -2 and 0 although the actual distribution of X  has a zero probability on this interval.

    Figure 1. Example of mixture distributions with their implied Gaussian unconditional distributions

    Source: LOIM. For illustrative purposes only.

    To mitigate the effect of regimes on a long-run risk-based portfolio, we introduce a new portfolio that accounts for the non-stationarities of the returns, induced by changing regimes, explicitly using this regime-level information to build a regime-resistant long-run allocation. Our regime-parity portfolio preserves the risk-diversification features of the risk-parity portfolio by relying on a regime-specific ERC solution but renders explicit the embedding of regimes by weighting the local ERC portfolios by the probability of each regime occurring. Thus, the regime-parity portfolio is a linear combination given by

     


     

    where M denotes the number of regimes,  the steady-state probability of regime , and is the ERC portfolio computed on the multivariate distribution conditional on being in regime . Of course, if the regimes are uninformative about the distribution of returns, the regime-parity portfolio coincides with the ERC portfolio as the conditional distributions are identical to the unconditional distribution. When such regimes exist and discriminate with respect to the data-generating process that animates returns, however, the two portfolios deviate from each another.  

    The probability-weighting of the local ERC portfolios has the advantage of being linear in the frequency of occurrence. A similar weighting scheme was used by Maheu and McCurdy (2009) when modelling the long-run distribution of equity returns in the presence of structural breaks. Interestingly, it also relates to the probability matching effect in the behavioural finance literature (see, for example, Kim and Kim (2022)) that influenced the adaptive markets hypothesis of Lo (2004). 

  • To illustrate the differences between the regime-parity and the risk-parity portfolios, we first consider a synthetically simplified example, considering volatility as the risk measure to break down. We assume that our investment universe is composed of a risky asset and a hedging asset that follow a conditionally Gaussian multivariate regime-switching model with two regimes: a stressed regime that rarely occurs and a calm regime that occurs frequently. More precisely, we assume the following dynamic for the assets’ excess returns:
     



    where
     




    and  is a Markov chain with the following transition probabilities matrix
     


    yielding the steady state probabilities   and . In the case of two assets, the solution of the ERC is explicit and given by

     
     

    Additionally, the unconditional mean of is given by  while the unconditional individual volatility of each asset  is given by 
     

     
     

    We can thus derive analytically the unconditional ERC portfolio and the regime-parity portfolio. Table 1 shows the weight of each asset in the different portfolios. Note that since the Sharpe ratio of the two assets are equal in regime 1 (the calm regime), the regime-specific ERC is locally optimal in the sense of Markowitz (see Maillard et al. (2010) and Ardia and Boudt (2015)). In that sense, the deviation of the unconditional ERC portfolio from the portfolio in regime 1 appears disproportionate with regards to the low probability of the stress regime occurring. On the contrary, the regime-parity portfolio deviates less while still adding some hedging assets to the portfolio to account for the possible occurrence of the stressed regime.

    Table 1. Weights of the different portfolios
     

     

    ERC regime 1

    ERC regime 2

    ERC unconditional

    Regime parity

    Asset 1

    83.33%

    87.50%

    86.79%

    83.71%

    Asset 2

    16.67%

    12.50%

    13.21%

    16.29%

    Source: LOIM. For illustrative purposes only.

    To analyse this deviation, figure 2 presents the weights of the hedging asset and the risk asset as a function of the steady-state probability of occurrence of the stress regime . Particularly striking is the very large deviation of the unconditional risk-parity portfolio, even for highly infrequent stressed regimes. On the contrary, the regime parity is by construction linearly updating with the unconditional regime probability and, linearly, goes from the risk-parity portfolio in regime 1 to the risk-parity solution in regime 2 as the regime becomes more frequent. This non-linear effect of the risk-parity portfolio stems from the inability of the unconditional moments to correctly capture both modes of the mixture distribution, whereas the regime-parity construction alleviates this effect.

    Figure 2. Portfolio composition as a function of the frequency of occurrence of the stress regime

    Source: LOIM. For illustrative purposes only.

    While the linearity-in-probability feature of the regime parity is helpful when tracking the individual regime-specific risk contributions in the total risk of the portfolio, the non-linearity of the unconditional ERC may prove useful when large shocks occur in the stress regime. 

    Figure 3 provides a counterargument, however. While the unconditional ERC presents a concave response to the increase in the stressed regime probability, its response to an increase in the magnitude of the risk in the stress regime is linear. Indeed, the figure presents the relative increase in the allocation to the hedging asset as a function of the risk asset volatility in the stress regime, keeping the frequency occurrence of the stress regime constant at 9%. In this case, the regime-parity portfolio presents a desired concave profile, being able to respond quickly to an increase in risk in the adverse regime but without distorting too sharply the final portfolio from the optimal portfolio in the more frequent calm regime. On the contrary, the unconditional ERC portfolio presents a linear sensibility to the risk in the adverse regime, artificially augmenting the weight of the hedging asset.

    Figure 3. Portfolio allocation to the hedging asset as a function of the risk asset volatility in an adverse regime

    Source: LOIM. For illustrative purposes only.
     

  • To illustrate the advantages of our portfolio construction, we present a set of applications based on real data. We consider different geographical markets (US, Eurozone, Japan, UK, Canada, Australia, China and Switzerland), each with three assets: a local equity index, a local sovereign bond index, and a local investment-grade corporate debt index. We assume a two-regime economy with expansion and recession phases. For the regime classification, we follow the NBER (National Bureau of Economic Research) and the CEPR (Centre for Economic Policy Research) for the US and the Eurozone respectively. We derive the regimes in the other economies through a standard regime-switching method applied to a set of classic business cycle domestic measures as there exists no consensus for dating recessions. Figure 4 presents the annualised outperformance of the regime-parity portfolio compared to the unconditional risk-parity portfolio.

    Figure 4. Annualised outperformance of the regime-parity portfolio against the unconditional ERC portfolio


    Source: LOIM. For illustrative purposes only.

    Although they prove interesting in the US and Canada, the results appear relatively disappointing for the other markets. We postulate that this absence of outperformance stems from the misidentification of regimes. Indeed, if regimes are uninformative for the conditional distribution of returns, the regime-parity portfolio coincides with the ERC portfolio, yielding the same performance in the end. 

    To illustrate the sensitivity of the regime-parity portfolio construction to the identification of regimes, we carry out a set of Monte Carlo experiments. Building on the illustrative model presented in section 2, we randomly and purposefully mis-specify a proportion of the regime identification, meaning that a proportion of the points used to compute the conditional moments are not correctly classified. Figure 5 presents the outperformance of the regime-parity portfolio compared to the unconditional risk-parity portfolio as a function of . We see that although the regime-parity portfolio is relatively resilient to mis-specified regimes, the outperformance disappears when the false discovery rate in the identification of the regime becomes large. 

    Figure 5. Outperformance of the regime-parity portfolio against the unconditional ERC portfolio as a function of regime mis-specification

    Source: LOIM. For illustrative purposes only.

     

  • The risk-parity approach provides a coherent allocation scheme to create diversified long-run portfolios. However, when returns are influenced by latent regimes such as recession-expansion phases or inflation shocks, these non-stationarities can affect the unconditional distribution underlying the portfolio construction, leading the risk-parity allocation to load too much risk on the hedging asset. 

    Our solution is the regime-parity portfolio, which is a linear combination between regime-specific risk-parity portfolios. We propose to weigh these regime-specific portfolios according to the steady-state probabilities of each regime, thus making use of the entire regime-level information. This new portfolio shows interesting features, notably better resistance to rare, yet adverse, regimes. The success of such an investment approach depends significantly on the accuracy of the regime retained to split the history of returns. This portfolio should clearly appeal to multi-asset portfolio managers because it improves the return-contribution balance within their long-run allocations.

  • Ardia, D., & Boudt, K. (2015). Implied expected returns and the choice of a mean–variance efficient portfolio proxy. Journal of Portfolio Management, 41(4), 68-81.

    Ardia, D., Boudt, K., & Nguyen, G. (2018). Beyond risk-based portfolios: balancing performance and risk contributions in asset allocation. Quantitative Finance, 18(8), 1249-1259.

    Blin, O., Ielpo, F., Lee, J., & Teiletche, J. (2020). Alternative risk premia timing: A point-in-time macro, sentiment, valuation analysis. Forthcoming in Journal of Systematic Investing.

    Bai, X., Scheinberg, K., & Tutuncu, R. (2016). Least-squares approach to risk parity in portfolio selection. Quantitative Finance, 16(3), 357-376.

    Boudt, K., Carl, P., & Peterson, B. G. (2012). Boudt, K., Carl, P., & Peterson, B. G. (2012). Asset allocation with conditional value-at-risk budgets. Journal of Risk, 15(3), 39-68.

    Guidolin, M., & Timmermann, A. (2006). An econometric model of nonlinear dynamics in the joint distribution of stock and bond returns. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 21(1), 1-22.

    Hamilton, J. D. (1989). A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica, 57(2), 357-384.

    Ielpo, F. (2012). Equity, credit and the business cycleApplied Financial Economics22(12), 939-954.

    Lo, A. W. (2004). The Adaptive Markets Hypothesis. Journal of Portfolio Management, 30(5), 15-29.

    Maheu, J. M., & McCurdy, T. H. (2000). Identifying bull and bear markets in stock returns. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 18(1), 100-112.

    Maheu, J. M., & McCurdy, T. H. (2009). How useful are historical data for forecasting the long-run equity return distribution? Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 27(1), 95-112.

    Maillard, S., Roncalli, T., & Teiletche, J. (2010). The properties of equally weighted risk contribution portfolios. The Journal of Portfolio Management, 36(4), 60-70.

    Pettenuzzo, D., & Timmermann, A. (2011). Predictability of stock returns and asset allocation under structural breaks. Journal of Econometrics, 164(1), 60-78.

    Pettenuzzo, D., & Timmermann, A. (2022). Corrigendum to “Predictability of stock returns and asset allocation under structural breaks”. Journal of Econometrics, 227(2), 513-517.

    Van Vliet, P., & Blitz, D. (2011). Dynamic strategic asset allocation: Risk and return across the business cycle. Journal of Asset Management12(5), 360-375.

sources.

1  From Euler homogeneous function theorem, if a function  is first-degree homogenous (ie verifying ), then we have the following decomposition:  .

important information.

For professional investors only

This document is issued by Lombard Odier Asset Management (Europe) Limited, authorised and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority (the “FCA”), and entered on the FCA register with registration number 515393. This document is approved at the date of publication.

Lombard Odier Investment Managers (“LOIM”) is a trade name.

This document is provided for information purposes only and does not constitute an offer or a recommendation to purchase or sell any security or service. It is not intended for distribution, publication, or use in any jurisdiction where such distribution, publication, or use would be unlawful. This material does not contain personalized recommendations or advice and is not intended to substitute any professional advice on investment in financial products. Before entering into any transaction, an investor should consider carefully the suitability of a transaction to his/her particular circumstances and, where necessary, obtain independent professional advice in respect of risks, as well as any legal, regulatory, credit, tax, and accounting consequences. This document is the property of LOIM and is addressed to its recipient exclusively for their personal use. It may not be reproduced (in whole or in part), transmitted, modified, or used for any other purpose without the prior written permission of LOIM. This material contains the opinions of LOIM, as at the date of issue.

UK regulation for the protection of retail clients in the UK and the compensation available under the UK Financial Services Compensation scheme does not apply in respect of any investment or services provided by an overseas person. A summary of investor rights and information on the integration of sustainability risks are available at: https://am.lombardodier.com/home/asset-management-regulatory-disc.html.

Neither this document nor any copy thereof may be sent, taken into, or distributed in the United States of America, any of its territories or possessions or areas subject to its jurisdiction, or to or for the benefit of a United States Person. For this purpose, the term "United States Person" shall mean any citizen, national or resident of the United States of America, partnership organized or existing in any state, territory or possession of the United States of America, a corporation organized under the laws of the United States or of any state, territory or possession thereof, or any estate or trust that is subject to United States Federal income tax regardless of the source of its income.

Source of the figures: Unless otherwise stated, figures are prepared by LOIM.

Although certain information has been obtained from public sources believed to be reliable, without independent verification, we cannot guarantee its accuracy or the completeness of all information available from public sources.

Views and opinions expressed are for informational purposes only and do not constitute a recommendation by LOIM to buy, sell or hold any security. Views and opinions are current as of the date of this presentation and may be subject to change. They should not be construed as investment advice.

No part of this material may be (i) copied, photocopied or duplicated in any form, by any means, or (ii) distributed to any person that is not an employee, officer, director, or authorised agent of the recipient, without Lombard Odier Asset Management (Europe) Limited prior consent.
©2023 Lombard Odier IM. All rights reserved.